The Arguments of "The Rice Import Liberalization
Agenda in Liberia"
By Geepu Nah Tiepoh
Sept 6, 2000
The need for economic research and analysis as prerequisite
for policy decisions is an elementary and obvious fact, which
we should waste no time to debate. And yet, some people have superfluously
stressed this need for policy research, as if others were not
aware of it. Every Liberian economic policy, not only agricultural
policy, requires research for its successful formulation and implementation.
This is a given, and we do not have time to waste on debating
whether or not Liberia should carry out agricultural policy research.
Project feasibility studies and cost/benefit analyses are routine
procedures that have to be conducted before instituting any economic
policies and programs. No serious Liberian government will embark
upon an economic policy or project without the appropriate research
to determine its implications for resource allocations and economic
and social returns. Unlike our critic, Harry Greaves, I have never
heard any serious Liberian economist advocating rice self-sufficiency
as a policy option without the need for research. And I, for one,
have never in any of my writings, especially those carried in
this magazine, proposed this policy option without the need for
appropriate research. So, why is he still insinuating that I am
calling for rice self-sufficiency without research, when in fact
he has been adequately informed that this is not my position?
Why is it that instead of debating the main issues raised in my
original submission, "The Rice
Import Liberalization Agenda: Some Critical Policy Issues",
our critic continues to avoid them, but quibble over elementary
and obvious matters? And although such diversionary attitude and
sophistry was brought to his attention in a previous rebuttal,
"Blinded by Free Trade and Comparative
Advantage Dogma", he has neither acknowledged nor amended
it in his latest rejoinder, "The
Continuing Debate about Self-Sufficiency in Rice Production for
Liberia". Not only did he refuse to address the critical
policy questions raised in the original piece, he was also unable
to identify where in that article I expressed "emotion-laden
cant, hype and theology about the need for Liberia to be self-sufficient
in rice", and where I advocated "policy prescriptions
purely on the basis of emotion", as he claimed in his earlier
reaction. Instead, he continues to perpetuate the distortion,
insinuation, and falsehood that I am advocating for rice self-sufficiency
without research.
Let it be known that I have nothing against our critic for being
"an advocate of free trade", as he professes. What I
have problem with is the apparent severity of his ideological
zealousness. It is still believed that his reaction to my original
article stemmed more from his free trade ideological convictions
than from any genuine desire to discuss the important policy issues
raised in that article. In his first reaction, "What's the
Case for Self-Sufficiency in Rice Production?", he was clearly
suggesting that the policy implications of import liberalization
discussed in the original article should not have been raised
in the first place because Liberia does not need rice self-sufficiency
since, according to him, the country can have its rice consumption
needs met through importation. Such is the kind of ideological
arrogance that I detest. Because of one's belief in free trade
he does not want others to have the freedom to criticize it! In
essence, he is precluding all other policy options, except those
in line with his free trade ideology. Thus, he was the one passing
policy judgement without research. If this was not the case, why
then has he persistently evaded the central arguments of the original
article? Why has he reduced the whole debate to the trivial issue
of how Liberia needs agricultural policy research? This is not
an issue to debate; it is an obvious and elementary requirement
of any economic policy making. My original article did not advocate
rice self-sufficiency without the need for research. Again,
can our critic show me where?
The main objective of the original article (and let me emphasize)
was to expose some of the policy contradictions and problems inherent
in the Government of Liberia's longstanding flirtation with rice
self-sufficiency and the present government's new policy of rice
import liberalization. Upon coming to power, Taylor had decried
Liberians for being too "lazy" to produce their own
rice and had threatened them that they would pay higher prices
for imported rice, if they did not become self-sufficient. Few
months later, this same government started a rice import liberalization
program aimed at removing all necessary barriers to importation
of rice to Liberia. Not only was such a shift self-contradictory,
but the new policy of rice import liberalization also contains
serious negative implications for macroeconomic stability and
the government's own dream of rice self-sufficiency. My article
was designed to expose some of these policy implications. Let
me put these questions to our critic: Isn't it true that a broader
policy of import liberalization, involving rice, petroleum, and
possibly other sectors of the economy (as envisaged by the government),
could have a destabilizing effect on the government's own objective
of fiscal restraint, in terms of revenue loss? In spite of its
commitment to balanced budgets, the government has been running
deficits since it came to power (about 0.5 percent of GDP for
1999). Broad-based import liberalization could lead to the loss
of government revenue and, if this happens, then balancing the
budget would be effected further from the expenditure side, possibly
exerting greater pressure on the already thin public and social
sectors of the economy. Isn't it true that cheaper importation
and influx of foreign rice and other commodities on to the Liberian
market could have a negative impact on Liberia's balance of payment,
and since the country now faces a binding external financing constraint
(huge external debt and so forth), government would most likely
resort to a fast devaluation of the Liberian dollar in order to
diminish such influx? Wouldn't this devaluation of the dollar,
in turn, possibly lead to increases in rice prices and inflation
in general? Finally, isn't it possible that if import liberalization
involves more economic sectors, then the overall level of import
restriction in the economy will substantially fall, and as the
economy grows and export earnings (foreign exchange) increase,
government could be tempted to allow more importation of foreign
rice and other commodities? And if such inflow of rice were so
strong that it penetrated rural households, wouldn't this have
a detrimental effect on rural subsistence farming?
Those were the policy issues that the original article was about.
Are these issues not worth discussing, just because international
trade is "free" and Liberia is assured of getting its
rice supply from foreign countries? Thank Allah, our critic has
now agreed with me that Liberia cannot rely solely on world markets
to deliver all of its rice consumption needs. In his latest rejoinder,
he wrote: "So, what are the alternatives between the extremes
of 100 percent importation and 100 percent self-sufficiency in
domestic production? The reality is that there are many people
in rural Liberia who are engaged in subsistence farming, including
rice production. Clearly they need help and some resources
should be directed at helping them. But devoting some resources
to assisting subsistence farmers to expand rice production is
a far cry from deploying very significant resources to
attain 100 percent self-sufficiency in rice production."
First, this statement is one of the generalized insinuations by
our critic that I detest. Have I ever written anywhere that Liberia
should strive for 100 percent self-sufficiency in rice production?
Second, by this statement, our critic has finally agreed with
me that Liberia cannot depend solely on the importation of rice,
but the country can also assist its rural farmers to contribute
to rice production. But if he agrees to this point, why then has
he accused me of "emotion-laden cant" just for discussing
the implications of rice import liberalization for rural subsistence
farmers? Okay, let us suppose, for the sake of argument, that
the country has agreed to import 80 percent of its rice consumption,
and the remaining 20 percent from rural subsistence farmers. Shouldn't
we still be concerned about the possible negative implications
of an economic policy that promotes unrestricted importation of
foreign rice? The only time the country may afford to ignore such
policy implications is perhaps when it imports all of its rice
consumption needs from abroad. So, you see, our critic cannot
have it both ways. He cannot be saying that rural farmers should
be encouraged to contribute to domestic rice production and then
crucify those who are concerned with the negative implications
of a policy that may endanger such rural economic contribution.
This is self-contradiction at its maximum!
With respect to Harry's continuous renditions about comparative
advantage and free trade, I have already provided an in-depth
analysis of the international operation of these theories in my
last rebuttal, "Blinded by Free Trade and Comparative Advantage
Dogma". Most types of comparative advantage are deliberately
constructed by nations. They are not handed down to countries
on silver platters. In fact, a careful examination of the history
of global economic relations indicates that the dominant powers
of the world economy had deliberately influenced the development
of present-day patterns of international trade. It is about time
that we stop viewing comparative advantage in static terms. Even
if Liberia does not have comparative advantage now in rice production,
does it mean that she can never have such an advantage in the
future? Did we have comparative advantage in rubber plantation
before Firestone? The acquisition of comparative advantage is
a dynamic and developmental process. Hence, to believe that Liberia
should abandon rice production once a cost/benefit analysis rules
that it has no comparative advantage is not only shortsighted
but also self-defeatist.
In previous analysis, it was made sufficiently clear that I am
not opposed to international trade. It is the extreme inequalities
underlying international trade and capital movement that annoy
me. Is it economically fair, or can we even call it free trade,
when some countries are pressured into opening their economies
wide to the consumer products of countries which restrict similar
flows to their economies? Can we say that there is a leveled playing
field in international trade when some countries are spending
billions of dollars in subsidies to restrict entry to their markets
while enforcing their entry into the markets of others? Our critic
appears to be less concerned about such inequalities. In his latest
submission, he writes: "There are many great and noble economic
practices in the West (to use a generalization) which we in Liberia
would do well to emulate. Broad-based price supports for special
interests, such as is accorded textiles and sugar in the United
States, butter and wine in some European countries, and, yes,
rice in Japan, are not amongst the practices which I think we
would be wise to emulate. The reasons these industries are protected
in the West often have more to do with politics than sound macro-economic
policy making." This conclusion that agricultural industries
in the West are protected more for political than macroeconomic
reasons is highly refutable. But let us agree for the benefit
of our critic that this is true. Isn't it still unfair to ask
Liberia not to emulate provision of price support to its industries
when countries with which she trades are providing such support
to theirs? When some countries are allowed to provide price support
to their industries and others are prevented from doing so, can
we say that the patterns of trade established among those countries
are truly based on comparative advantage and free trade? I do
not believe so.
Finally, in the context of the Liberian economy, as explained
in my last rebuttal, there is a strong link between food self-sufficiency
and food security. The exact rates of self-sufficiency that Liberia
could strive for, say 35 percent, 50 percent, or 75 Percent, or
whatever, are to be determined from economic studies and research.
Nevertheless, in order for the country to be secure of its rice
and other major food supplies, there are very compelling economic
reasons why she should strive for such food security through raising
its overall self-sufficiency rates in the production of not only
rice but also other major food commodities, such as cassava, sweet
potatoes, and yams. Paramount among these reasons is the fact
that Liberia's current sources of export earnings and foreign
capital inflows are not reliable, stable, and everlasting. Our
critic's statement that "...if Liberia did not produce one
grain of rice..., the country's food security would still not
be in jeopardy" can only be true if these sources
of foreign exchange were dependable, stable and sufficient. In
order for the country to resign itself to importing most of its
major food supplies, it must not only have a lasting and sufficient
source of other resources to export to world markets, but such
resources must also be valued at adequate and stable world prices.
Do we have a lasting source of such nonrenewable mineral resources
as iron ore? Are we managing our tropical forests the right way
so that they provide a continuous source of exports? Can we continuously
depend upon rubber export to pay for our food? From the existing
knowledge and past experience, these export sources are not only
exhaustible, but they have been insufficient and unreliable. Even
if the answer to each of the above questions were 'yes', does
Liberia have any control over how these traditional exports are
valued on world markets? There is a great deal of volatility in
these markets, and a small country, like ours, has virtually no
influence on how its exports should be priced on world markets.
Moreover, Liberia's unsustainable external debt burdens (e.g.,
a debt service-to-export ratio of 70.8 percent) now render most
foreign capital flow to the country uncertain.
It is in light of the above and other economic reasons that Liberia
cannot solely rely on importation of its major foods. We do not
have industrial products to sell to world markets, and the export
base we have is very narrow. From such a narrow base we have been
unable to derive all of the financial resources needed to pay
for our food imports and other foreign inputs required for economic
development. And partly because of this, we are now fatally indebted
to foreign countries. Now, should we still continue to rely on
this dwindling base which may soon collapse under us, or should
we strive to do something different and possibly improve our chance
of survival? If we agree that the external sector of our economy
is deficient, then doesn't it make sense that we should supplement
it with a strong domestic sector capable of seriously contributing
to the production of our major foods? Finally, to our friends
who are concerned, rightfully so, about comparative advantage
and resource allocation, which of these two activities is Liberia,
with all its fertile and adequately watered land and no flooding,
capable of achieving with the least technical, financial, institutional,
and international political barriers: Establishing and owning
a car manufacturing plant in Monrovia, or providing a rice-processing
mill to rural farmers in Tappita? A food for thought.
Geepu Nah Tiepoh is a development economist and consultant with ACLAD Development, Canada.